Horticulture is an important component of agriculture accounting for a very significant share in the Indian economy. Rising consumer income and changing lifestyles are creating bigger markets for high-value horticultural products in India as well as throughout the world. Among these, the most important high-value export products are fruits and vegetables. This study was conducted to analyze the comparative advantage and competitiveness of pomegranate and gherkin which are the important foreign exchange earner among fruit and vegetable crops exported from India.
The primary data was collected from Tumkur and Bijapur district of Karnataka, India and secondary data was collected from concerned government institutions, APEDA and also from exporters of fruits and vegetables. The Policy Analysis Matrix (PAM) was selected as the analytical tool to analyse the export competitiveness, comparative advantage, and the degree of government interventions in the production and export of gherkin and pomegranate. The policy distortions were measured through indicators of PAM. Garret ranking technique was used to analyse the constraints in the production and export of the selected crops.
EPC of Gherkin (0.5) and pomegranate (0.45) values which found to be less than one indicates that producers are not protected through policy interventions. Whereas DRC and PCR values of Gherkin and Pomegranate respectively shows positive, social as well as private profit which indicates that, India has a competitive and comparative advantage in their production. The result for Garret ranking in case of gherkin shows that skilled labour and lack of superior quality are the major constraints in production and export of gherkin respectively. In case of pomegranate non availability of skilled labour, high incidence of pest and diseases, lack of transportation facilities, high residual effect of pesticide are the major constrain in production and export.
The overall result shows that the cultivation as well as export of gherkin and pomegranate is economically profitable and efficient.
Key Words: Gherkin, Pomegranate, PAM, EPC and DRC
Variable | Definition |
---|---|
APEDA | Agricultural and Processed Food Products Export Development Authority |
CIF | Cost Insurance and Freight |
Crores | 10 million |
DRC | Domestic Resource Cost |
EPC | Effective Protection Coefficient |
EU | European Union |
FAOSTAT | Food and Agriculture Organization Statistics |
FOB | Free On Border |
FYM | Farm Yard Manure |
ha | Hectares |
HEIA | Horticulture Export Improvement Association |
kg | Kilogram |
MHA | Million Hectare |
MT | Million Tons |
NHB | National Horticulture Board |
NPCI | Nominal Protection Coefficient on Inputs |
NPCO | Nominal Protection Coefficient on Outputs |
NPV | Net Present Value |
PAM | Policy Analysis Matrix |
PCR | Private Cost Ratio |
INR | Indian Rupees |
UAE | United Arab Emirates |
UK | United Kingdom |
UNCOMTRADE | United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics |
UNFAO | United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization |
USA | United States of America |
Indian agriculture is vested with the herculean responsibility of feeding over more than one billion people. Out of total, 72% of India's population live in rural areas, further three-fourth of the rural populations depend on agriculture and allied activities for their livelihoods. The present growth in agriculture in India is hassle with problems most importantly, agricultural growth slowed down to 2.1% between 1998-99 and 2004-05. It is largely due to a decline in the food grain sector that grew at merely 0.6%. Given the high dependence of the poor on agriculture, the stagnation in this sector is currently threatening to stall poverty reduction in India .
Given the present scenario, the immediate question to be addressed is how agricultural growth can be accelerated. The question can be answered through by diversifying the consumption pattern towards high value agricultural commodities in general and high value horticultural products in particular such as fruits and vegetables. In recent years there has been a great deal of interest among policymakers and trade analysts in the role of horticultural products as a principle means of agricultural diversification and foreign exchange earnings in developing countries. Horticultural products have high income elasticity of demand as income goes up the demand raises rapidly. It grows especially in middle and high income developing countries. As people are more cautious on health and nutrition, there is a paradigm shift from high fat, high cholesterol foods such as meat and live stock products to low fat and low cholesterol foods such as fruits and vegetables. As a result, the world has changed its attention towards high value agricultural products. Hence, it is crucial to be competitive in the world market to reap the potential gains of increased and growing world demand for horticultural products such as fruits and vegetables. Thus, the purpose of the present study attempts to evaluate the consequences of international trade and competitiveness of Indian horticulture with special reference to pomegranate and gherkin crops. In the recent past, these two crops got high export potential and earned good foreign exchange.
There are many studies related to export of horticultural crops especially fruits and vegetables from India. Chiniwar (2009) explained the numerous opportunities and challenges of the horticulture sector and observed that there is a tremendous potential for Indian pomegranates in the global market. He examined the growth of pomegranate exports from India. The study revealed that the growth of pomegranate exports from India is moderate in comparision to the potential for its exports. Tamanna et al. (1999) examined the export potential of selected fruits from India by using Nominal Protection Coefficient (NPC). The results indicate that the exports of Indian fruits are highly competitive in the world market. Nalini et al. (2008) observed that India has made tremendous progress in the export of cucumber and gherkin products during the past 15 years (1990-2005). The export has increased by about 129 times with an impressive annual compound growth rate of 37.46 percent, as against only 4.38 percent in the world market. An increasing and high value of Revealed Comparative Advantage (RCA) and a positive and increasing value for Revealed Symmetric Comparative Advantage (RSCA) have indicated high potential for their export. One percent increase in volume of international trade in cucumber and gherkin may increase the demand from India by 5.96 percent. This indicates that India is highly competitive in the export of cucumber and gherkin. It has ample scope to further increase its export. Gulati et al. (1994) analyzed the export competitiveness of selected agricultural commodities and identified the constraints in the export of fresh fruits, vegetables, processed fruits and vegetables.
The above studies are related to export performance, growth, and constraints of fruits and vegetables. Most of these studies focused on aspects pertaining to export of fruits and vegetables. There are no studies on export policy especially related to efficiency and comparative advantage in world market. Therefore, the aim of the present study is to analyze the export competitiveness of pomegranate and gherkin by using Policy Analysis Matrix (PAM). The study has a high scope because competitiveness has become a key issue in the international market for export development of fruits and vegetables.
In the present study, the export competitiveness of high value horticultural crops of India is analyzed. To be very precise, the study analyzes the competitiveness of gherkin and pomegranate in the world market. It also compares the advantages and constraints in the export of these crops with the following objectives and proposed hypothesis, which will be tested based on the results and conclusion.
Specific objectives
Hypothesis
The study contains the results of the analysis of export competitiveness of horticultural crops in India. In the present study, opportunities are analyzed, constraints in production and export of gherkins and pomegranates from India. We further analyze the competitiveness and comparative advantage of these two crops in international market. The detailed information of this analysis is discussed in the following sections of the study.
The first section of the thesis gives us an introduction and background on the nature of the problem, facts on the dynamics and underlying causes diversifying the consumption pattern of high value horticultural commodities. Further, a brief overview of existing studies on Indian agricultural and horticultural growth, export performance, and constraints will be discussed. The research question is broken down into specific objectives and a possible hypothesis has been put forth.
The second section of the thesis will give a general overview of fruit and vegetable scenario in the world as well as in India. The section also explains the importance of selected fruit and vegetable by considering production, export and foreign exchange earnings which will help us to understand the export competitiveness of these crops from India.
The third section deals with methodological framework which deals with the concepts and competitiveness of high value horticultural crops from India focusing on the application of PAM model for the study. In the same chapter, the current literature and outline of the major definitions for competitiveness and comparative advantage are studied. The above proposed model will be used as a tool to address the research objectives followed by data description.
Fourth section highlights the findings of the research from the proposed model using collected information on pomegranate and gherkin cultivation, and their export. Finally, the proposed hypothesis is tested and the results inferred.
The final section summarizes the whole research findings and provides meaningful policy implications.
2.1.1 High value agricultural production
Rising consumer income and changing lifestyles are creating bigger markets for high value agricultural products throughout the world. Among these, the most important high value export sector is horticulture, especially fruits and vegetables. The growing markets for these products present an opportunity for the farmers of developing countries to diversify their production out of staple grains and raise their income. Annual growth rates on the order of 8 to 10 percent in high value agricultural products is promising development (Fig.1), as the production, processing and marketing of these products create a lot of needed employment in rural areas. The rapid growth in high value exports has been part of fundamental and broad reaching trend towards globalization of the agro food system. Dietary changes, trade reform and technical changes in the food industry have contributed to the growth of high value agriculture and trade (World Bank, 2008).
2.1.2 World production of fruit and vegetables
The production of fruit and vegetables all over the world grew by 30 percent between 1980 to 1990 and by 56 percent between 1990 to 2003. Much of this growth occurred in China where production grew up by 134 percent in 1980 and climbed to 200 percent by 1990 (UNFAO 2003). At present the world production of fruits and vegetables reached to 512 MT and 946.7MT respectively (Table 1 & 5).
Vegetables: China is currently the world's largest producer of vegetables, with the production 448.9 MT with an area of 23.9 MHA (47%) (Table 1), whereas India is in the 2nd position with the production of 125.8 MT with an area of 7.8 MHA (13%) followed by USA (4%), Turkey (3%) etc (Indian Horticulture Database, 2008) (Fig.2). Among the vegetable crops gherkin is considered for the study as it is one of the most important vegetable all over the world. Table 2 shows the international production of cucumber and gherkin from different parts of the world during 2007-08. China, Turkey, Iran, Russia and USA are the world largest producers of cucumber and gherkin (Table 3), whereas India position in the production is 34th but it reached 1st (Table 3) and 55th (Table 4) position in export of provisionally preserved and fresh cucumber gherkin respectively.
Table 1 Major vegetables producing countries in the world (2007-08)
Country | Area(000 ha) | Production(000 MT) | Productivity(MT/ha) |
---|---|---|---|
China | 23936 | 448983 | 19 |
India | 7803 | 125887 | 16 |
USA | 1333 | 38075 | 29 |
Turkey | 996 | 24454 | 25 |
Russia | 970 | 16516 | 17 |
Egypt | 598 | 16041 | 27 |
Iran | 641 | 15993 | 25 |
Italy | 528 | 13587 | 26 |
Spain | 379 | 12676 | 33 |
Japan | 433 | 11938 | 28 |
Others | 16957 | 222625 | 13 |
Total | 54573 | 946774 |
Source: Indian Horticulture Database (2008)
Table 2 International production of cucumber and gherkin (2007-08)
Country | Production (MT) | Share (%) |
---|---|---|
China | 28062000 | 62.9 |
Turkey | 1875919 | 4.21 |
Iran, Islamic republic | 1720000 | 3.86 |
Russian federation | 1410000 | 3.16 |
USA | 920000 | 2.06 |
Ukraine | 775000 | 1.74 |
Japan | 634000 | 1.42 |
Egypt | 615000 | 1.38 |
Indonesia | 600000 | 1.34 |
Spain | 510000 | 1.14 |
Mexico | 500000 | 1.12 |
Poland | 492000 | 1.10 |
Iraq | 480000 | 1.08 |
Netherland | 445000 | 1.00 |
India | 120000 | 0.27 |
Others | 5452024 | 12.22 |
World | 44610943 | 100 |
Source: Author, FAO (2008)
Table 3 Major exporting countries of fresh cucumber and gherkin (2007)
Country | Value (USD) | Share (%) |
---|---|---|
Spain | 557088 | 30.13 |
Mexico | 437369 | 23.65 |
Netherland | 419824 | 22.70 |
Canada | 81707 | 4.42 |
Germany | 44437 | 2.40 |
Turkey | 40300 | 2.18 |
Greece | 38920 | 2.10 |
Iran | 27768 | 1.50 |
Belgium | 25361 | 1.37 |
USA | 16313 | 0.88 |
India | 235 | 0.01 |
Others | 159815 | 8.64 |
World | 1849137 |
Source: Data from Agricultural and Processed food products Export
development Authority (APEDA), India.
Table 4 Major exporting countries of preserved cucumber and gherkin
Country | Value (USD) | Share (%) |
---|---|---|
India | 33476 | 49.39 |
China | 16754 | 24.72 |
Turkey | 4193 | 6.19 |
Netherlands | 3397 | 5.01 |
Belgium | 2670 | 3.94 |
Vietnam | 40300 | 2.11 |
Sri Lanka | 1003 | 1.48 |
Germany | 925 | 1.37 |
Spain | 596 | 0.88 |
USA | 992 | 0.87 |
World | 65040 |
Source: U.N COMTRADE (2007)
Fruits: World fruit production has steadily risen for the past four years (see Appendix 3 ). Table 5 shows the largest fresh fruit producers from different countries during 2007-08. China is the world's largest fruit producer, producing 19 percent of the world fruits. India ranks second in the list of world producer accounting 12 percent of the world's production followed by Brazil, where 7 percent of the world's fruit was grown. (Figure 3) As production is increasing in China at alarming rate compare to other top producing countries. Production growth almost averaged 6 percent per year in China, while production growth in India averaged 2.73 percent per year. The EU experienced the lower annual growth rate of 0.89 percent. Whereas, the production in USA and Brazil has been relatively constant over the period, with average annual growth rates of 0.61 percent for the former and 0.34 percent for the later. Other countries Mexico, South Africa and Chile have experienced slightly higher average annual production growth rates of 2.12, 2.56 and 1.3 percent respectively over the same period (FAOSTAT 2008). Among all fruits pomegranate is considered for the present study. Figure 4 shows India is the world largest producer of pomegranate with 900 MT (36%) followed by Iran (31%), Iraq (3%), USA (4%) etc. Over the years India's export rate for pomegranate has grown steadily to worth of INR0.61 million (US$13741) in 2007-08 with the share of 1.2 percent (Table 6).
Table 5 Major fruit producing countries in the world (2007-08)
Country | Area(000 ha) | Production(000 MT) | Productivity(MT/ha) |
---|---|---|---|
China | 9587 | 94418 | 10 |
India | 5775 | 63503 | 11 |
Brazil | 1777 | 36818 | 21 |
USA | 1168 | 24962 | 21 |
Italy | 1246 | 17891 | 14 |
Spain | 1835 | 15293 | 8 |
Mexico | 1100 | 15041 | 14 |
Turkey | 1049 | 12390 | 12 |
Iran | 1256 | 12102 | 10 |
Indonesia | 846 | 11615 | 14 |
Others | 22841 | 208036 | 9 |
Total | 48481 | 512070 |
Source: FAO & Indian Horticulture Database (2008)
Table 6 Pomegranate export from different parts of the world (2007)
Country | Value (USD) | Share (%) |
---|---|---|
Thailand | 172781 | 15.06 |
Spain | 138911 | 12.11 |
Vietnam | 84532 | 7.37 |
Mexico | 67739 | 5.91 |
Netherlands | 63858 | 5.57 |
Madagascar | 53822 | 4.69 |
Israel | 45219 | 3.94 |
Uzbekistan | 44128 | 3.85 |
Colombia | 40459 | 3.53 |
Azerbaijan | 37977 | 3.31 |
France | 36975 | 3.22 |
Germany | 17750 | 1.55 |
India | 13741 | 1.20 |
Others | 309565 | 27.45 |
World | 1127457 | 100 |
Source: Agricultural and Processed Food Products Export
Development Authority (APEDA), India
Horticulture is an important component of agriculture accounting for a very significant share in the Indian economy. It is identified as one of the potential sector for harnessing India's competitive advantage in international trade. Further it prepares India to achieve an overall trade target of 1% or more in the share of world trade. Meanwhile, making the country self-sufficient in the last few decades, horticulture has played a very significant role in earning foreign exchange through export.
Horticultural crops cover approximately 8.5 percent of total cropped area (20 MHA) (Table 7) with annual production of 207 MT, and productivity of 10.3 MT per hectare during the year 2007-08 (FAO & Indian Horticulture Database 2008). Among the horticultural crops fruits and vegetables play an important role, whereas exports of fruits and vegetables have increased over the years (Table 8). During 2004-05 export of fruits and vegetables was INR 13637.13 million as against INR 24116.57 million during 2006-07 (APEDA, 2008)
Table 7 Area, production and productivity of horticultural crops in India
Year |
Area (MHA) |
Production (MT) |
Productivity (MT/ha) ) |
---|---|---|---|
2001-02 | 16.6 | 145.8 | 8.8 |
2002-03 | 16.3 | 144.4 | 8.9 |
2003-04 | 19.2 | 153.3 | 21 |
2004-05 | 21.1 | 170.8 | 8.1 |
2005-06 | 18.7 | 182.8 | 9.8 |
2006-07 | 19.4 | 191.8 | 9.9 |
2007-08 | 20.1 | 207.0 | 10.3 |
Source: FAO & Indian Horticulture Database (2008)
Table 8 Export of horticultural produce in India
Products | 2004-05 | 2005-06 | 2006-07 | |||
Quantity | Value | Quantity | Value | Quantity | Value | |
Floriculture & seeds | 34496 | 2871 | 42659 | 3922 | 50048 | 7713 |
Fresh Fruits & vegetables | 1296530 | 13637 | 1465040 | 16587 | 1983873 | 24117 |
Processed fruits & vegetables | 325293 | 9614 | 501826 | 13595 | 549949 | 17316 |
Total | 1656319 | 261227 | 2009525 | 341051 | 258387 | 491459 |
Source: APEDA, India Note: Qty: MT, value : Million INR
Vegetables: In vegetable production, India is next to China with a production of 125.8 million tonnes from 7.8 million hectares with a share of 13 percent in relation to world production (Table 9). The per capital consumption of vegetables is 120 grams per day (APEDA 2009). In case of Fresh vegetable India's export has been increased from INR 433.14 Crore in 2006-07 to Rs 489.49 Crore in 2007-08. Major Export Destinations of these vegetables are UAE, UK, Nepal, and Saudi Arabia. (APEDA, 2009)
Table 9 Area, production and productivity of vegetable crops in India
Year |
Area (MHA) |
Production (MT) |
Productivity (MT/ha) ) |
---|---|---|---|
2001-02 | 6156 | 88622 | 14.4 |
2002-03 | 6092 | 84815 | 13.9 |
2003-04 | 6082 | 88334 | 14.5 |
2004-05 | 6744 | 101246 | 15.0 |
2005-06 | 7213 | 111399 | 15.4 |
2006-07 | 7584 | 115011 | 15.2 |
2007-08 | 7803 | 125887 | 16.1 |
Source: FAO & Indian Horticulture Database (2008)
Among all vegetables gherkin is considered for the present study due to following reasons. India's export of gherkin has been steadily increased since 1997-98. It accounts for 24,490 tonnes of gherkins having an export potential of INR 50.27 crore as against 35,242 tonnes worth of INR 69.86 crore in 1999-2000 (Venkatesh, 2003). In recent year gherkin export has been increased to 61.5 million tonnes with a trade value of INR1465.5 million during 2007-08 (UNFAO Export Data, 2009).
2.2.1 Production and export importance of gherkin in India
Gherkin crop is being selected for the present study. It is regarded as HEIA crop especially a hybrid crop. Gherkin cultivation and processing started in India in the early' 90s and presently cultivated over 19,500 acres in the three southern states of Karnataka, Tamil Nadu and Andhra Pradesh. Although gherkin can grow virtually in any part of the country, the ideal conditions required for growth prevail in these three states where the growing season extends throughout the year. It requires adequate water and temperature between 15-36 degree centigrade and the right type of soil. The crop takes 85 days to reach the required maturity level. Productivity is approximately four to five tonnes per acre and the best months are from February to March followed by June to August. India is a major exporter of provisionally preserved gherkin. Table 10 & 11 shows the cucumber and gherkin export from India. In India, Karnataka stands first in export, where cultivation is steadily growing since 2001-02 accounting for a worth of INR 1200 million. During 2006-07 gherkins accounts to INR 3133 million which has been exported (Table 12).
Table 10 Cucumber and gherkin exports from India (2007-08)
Country | Value( Million INR) | Quantity (Tonnes) | Share (%) ) |
---|---|---|---|
UAE | 1.96 | 142.75 | 17.55 |
Bangladesh | 1.92 | 290.00 | 17.17 |
Netherland | 1.78 | 93.10 | 15.92 |
Russia | 1.66 | 83.50 | 14.91 |
Estonia | 0.80 | 43.94 | 7.17 |
Nepal | 0.75 | 74.42 | 6.75 |
Oman | 0.75 | 70.00 | 6.74 |
Spain | 0.55 | 31.82 | 4.95 |
France | 0.47 | 20.21 | 4.27 |
Others | 0.51 | 26.42 | 4.56 |
Total | 11.20 | 876.18 | 100 |
Source: APEDA, 2009
Table 11 Preserved cucumber and gherkin exports from India (2007-08)
Country | Value( Million INR) | Quantity (Tonnes) | Share (%) ) |
---|---|---|---|
France | 365.52 | 12299.91 | 25.13 |
Spain | 253.02 | 9904.35 | 17.40 |
USA | 245.78 | 11296.19 | 16.90 |
Belgium | 182.40 | 6089.27 | 12.54 |
Russia | 125.17 | 6990.87 | 8.61 |
Canada | 52.59 | 2640.41 | 3.62 |
Australia | 51.68 | 2983.83 | 3.55 |
Netherlands | 24.72 | 1507.85 | 1.70 |
Italy | 21.90 | 751.58 | 1.50 |
Others | 131.47 | 6173.49 | 9.04 |
Total | 1454.29 | 60637.78 | 100 |
Source: APEDA, 2009
Table 12 Export performance of gherkin in Karnataka state over the years
Year | Value (Million INR) |
2001-02 | 1200 |
2002-03 | 1390 |
2003-04 | 1407 |
2004-05 | 1413 |
2005-06 | 2139.6 |
2006-07 | 3133.4 |
Source: APEDA, India
Fruits: Fresh fruits production in India cover an area of 5.7 MHA with the production of 63.5 MT in 2007-08 (Table 13). India's total export of Fresh Fruits, except grapes and mangoes was Rs 304.53 Crore in 2007-08. Major export destinations for fresh fruits are UAE, Bangladesh, Netherlands, Saudi Arabia and Nepal.
India is the second largest producer of fruits after China, with the production of 54.4 million tonnes of fruits from an area of 5.6 million hectares. A large variety of fruits are grown in India, of which mango, banana, citrus, guava, grape, pineapple, pomegranate and apple are the major ones (Table 14). Although fruit are grown throughout the country, the major fruit growing states are Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Uttar Pradesh and Gujarat. Karnataka is the second largest producer of pomegranates after Maharashtra, which grows about 6 Lakh metric tonnes cultivated in 93,000 hectares (Business standard June 17th 2009)
Table 13 Area, production and productivity of fruit crops in India
Year | Area(000 ha) | Production(000 MT) | Productivity(MT/ha) |
---|---|---|---|
2001-02 | 4010 | 43001 | 10.7 |
2002-03 | 3788 | 45203 | 11.9 |
2003-04 | 4661 | 45942 | 9.9 |
2004-05 | 5049 | 50867 | 10.1 |
2005-06 | 5324 | 55356 | 10.4 |
2006-07 | 5554 | 59563 | 10.7 |
2007-08 | 5775 | 63503 | 11.0 |
Source: FAO & Indian Horticulture Database (2008)
Table 14 Area and production estimates of fruit crops in India 2006-07
Fruit crops | Area (000’ha) | Production (000’MT) |
---|---|---|
Mango | 2154 | 13734 |
Apple | 252 | 1624 |
Banana | 604 | 20998 |
Citrus | 798 | 7145 |
Guava | 176 | 1830 |
Grapes | 65 | 1685 |
Litchi | 65 | 403 |
Papaya | 72 | 2482 |
Pineapple | 86 | 1362 |
Pomegranate | 117 | 840 |
Sapota | 149 | 1216 |
Others | 1016 | 6244 |
Total | 5554 | 59563 |
Source: National Horticulture Board (2008) https://nhb.gov.in/
2.2.2 Production and export importance of pomegranate in India
Pomegranate (Punica granatum L.) is one of the most important commercial fruit crop of India. It was chosen as a symbol for the 18th International Horticultural Congress which was held in India in the year 1970. Though the production of pomegranate is location specific, its consumption is widespread. Pomegranate is an ancient fruit which is commonly known as 'Anar', 'Dalim' and 'matulum', and is a favorite table fruit of tropical and subtropical countries around the world. It is an important fruit crop of arid and semi-arid regions in India. Apart from being a good table fruit, it has therapeutic values and good keeping qualities. Pomegranate belongs to the family Punicaceae and it is thought to be indigenous to the region of Iran, where it was first cultivated around 2000 B.C. later spread to the shores of Mediterranean (Asaph Goor, 1967). Among fruits, pomegranate is the major fruit crop to be exported and main reason attributed are good exports potential and fetched high good foreign exchange. During the period 2007-08 India exported 35175 tons of fruits worth INR 911 million to different parts of the world (APEDA 2009) (Table 15) with an area of 0.1 MHA and production 0.8 MT during 2006-07 (Table, 14). In Karnataka it is cultivated in the districts of Chitradurga, Bangalore, Mysore, Belgaum, Bijapur, Kolar and Tumkur (Anon. 1995). It is the second largest producer with a total area under cultivation around 0.01 MHA with a production of 0.14 MT during 2007-08 (NHB, 2009).
Table 15 Pomegranate exports from India
Country | Value( Million INR) | Quantity (Tonnes) | Share (%) ) |
---|---|---|---|
UAE | 255.88 | 11972.98 | 28.06 |
Netherlands | 218.98 | 7210.23 | 24.01 |
U.K | 80.43 | 1566.87 | 8.82 |
Saudi Arabia | 59.14 | 2766.55 | 6.49 |
Russia Federation | 50.67 | 1007.40 | 5.56 |
Belgium | 36.06 | 1521.83 | 3.95 |
Egypt | 23.84 | 593.23 | 2.61 |
Bangladesh | 23.81 | 2034.14 | 2.61 |
Canada | 18.95 | 586.15 | 2.08 |
Spain | 14.04 | 900.23 | 1.54 |
Others | 130.11 | 5015.53 | 14.26 |
Total | 911.94 | 35175.17 | 100 |
Source: APEDA, India
This Section defines the theory and concepts behind export competitiveness of selected fruits and vegetable with special emphasis on policy analysis matrix model to know whether the country has comparative advantage in exporting the commodities or not. It also measures the efficiency and export competitiveness of the selected crops in world market.
In this section, different concepts of costs and returns used in the study are presented. Farmers are more informed with the concept of acres rather than hectares. Hence I have also used the same and the conversion of acres to hectares is given below.
2.47106 acres = 1 hectare
3.1.1 Cost of cultivation of gherkin and pomegranate
The total cost is being divided into two components, viz. variable costs and fixed costs in case of gherkin. In case of pomegranate it's divided into three components variable costs, fixed costs and establishment costs.
Pomegranate is perennial crops require huge investment to establish the garden. The period of establishment was considered as one year. The establishment costs include, land preparation costs (ploughing, harrowing, clod threshing, leveling.), fencing (local or electrified), planting layers cost, transport of planting layers, opening of pits (2 x 2 x 2 feet), costs on planting and pit filling, and staking. The above said establishment costs were incurred only during first year.
A. Variable costs
These costs comprised of costs incurred on variable inputs such as seeds, farmyard manure, fertilizers, plant protection chemicals, labor, irrigation, staking materials and interest on working capital. In case of pomegranate other than the above costs pruning cost, weeding cost, harvesting cost, packing cost, cost of transportation of fruits, and the irrigation cost are also included. The computation of different terms of variable cost components is follows. The cost of seeds, fertilizers, Plant protection chemicals was computed by using the actual price paid by the sample farmers. The value of farmyard manure was imputed by considering the rates prevailing in the locality at the time of its application. Irrigation cost includes electricity charges plus maintenance charges paid by the respondents and the same has been apportioned based on the area under the crop concerned. Staking materials includes the cost of wooden poles, threads, which were used for staking the plant. The actual price paid by the farmers was used to compute the cost of staking materials. The cost of labour was computed by taking the wage rates paid by the sample farmers for human labour. The same wage rates were used while computing the imputed cost of family labour. When farmers provide food along with wages, the cost of food was computed based on the estimation of the farmers. Interest on working capital was calculated at the rate of 8 per cent for the duration of the crop, on the total value of seeds, manure, fertilizers, plant protection chemicals, staking materials, human labour (based on the interest rates charged by the financial institutions).
B. Fixed costs
These include depreciation on farm implements and machinery, interest on fixed capital and rental value of land.
Depreciation on each capital equipment and machinery owned by the farmers and used for land cultivation was calculated for each individual farmer separately, based on the purchase value using the straight line method. Thus the
Annual depreciation= (Purchase value-Junk value)/(Usefull life of the asset)
The average life of the asset as indicated by each farmer was used in the computation of depreciation. The average value of the asset after its useful life as estimated by respondents was considered for calculation of junk value. The depreciation cost of each equipment was apportioned to the crop based on its percentage use.
Interest charges on fixed capital were calculated at the rate of 10 per cent, as fixed deposits in commercial banks would fetch the above mentioned rate of interest. The items considered under fixed capital are implements and machinery. Interest was considered on the value of these assets after deducting the depreciation for the year. No interest was charged on land value since the rental value of owned land was considered. Then the amount so calculated was apportioned to the crop acreage for the duration of the crop.
Rental value of the land was calculated at the prevailing rate per acre per annum in the locality
3.1.2 Returns
Gross returns: Gross returns were obtained by multiplying the total product with the price realized.
Net returns: Net returns were obtained by deducting the total costs incurred from the gross returns obtained.
Competitiveness is a word and a common terminology applied in any firms, sectors, industries, regions and states there is no single definition for competitiveness which is universally accepted. Murphy stated that competitiveness focus on the sustained increase in productivity in the sector as a result of better business strategies and improved micro and macro economic conditions. Theoretically, competitiveness usually refers to characteristics that permit a firm to compete effectively with other firms across nations.
Measures of competitiveness include either a technical component (productivity or efficiency) or a relative price component (prices of inputs and outputs or private versus social prices) or both (Zawalinska 2000).
Vlachos (2001) stated that international competitiveness has the ability of a country to produce goods and services that meet the demand of international markets, and simultaneously maintain and expand the real incomes of its citizens.
Gorton and Davidova (2001) explained the competitiveness by using the European commission's definition that competitiveness as the ability of a country to increase its share of domestic and export markets where a country has a comparative advantage in a product more so it can produce at a lower opportunity cost than other countries. There are two main factors underlying international competitiveness. The ability to compare in international markets depends upon the price competitiveness or on product quality.
A country is said to have a comparative advantage in the production of tradable good if that countries production is efficient if not it has a comparative disadvantage. The concept of comparative advantage has two meaning efficiency of production is being compared among two or more trading nations, where nations with the lowest opportunity costs are relatively more efficient and have a comparative advantage. The other meaning of comparative advantage is referred to the efficiency of different kinds of production within the domestic economy, which are compared in terms of earnings or savings as a unit of foreign exchange.
In fact, competitiveness and comparative advantage are closely related terms. Competitiveness includes market distortions whereas comparative advantage does not (Frohberg and Hartmann, 1997). According to Kannapiran and Fleming (1999) "competitiveness measures the efficiency of commercial activities of individual producers and firms in the international markets" while "comparative advantage indicates the efficiency of resource allocation at the national level". The recent research on the competitiveness of transition countries, one of the most often cited definition of competitiveness is that of Freebairn (1996) who states that: "Competitiveness is an indicator of the ability to supply goods and services to the location and form. Simultaneously they are sought by buyers, at prices that are as good as or better than those of other potential suppliers, while earning at least the opportunity cost of returns on resources employed". Basically, the definition embodies both concepts. Competitiveness is the ability to gain and maintain a market share. The concept of comparative advantage includes also opportunity costs and is, hence, a longer-term measure, and is rather an indicator for efficient allocation of resources. In the case of perfect competition, homogeneous products, perfect information, and the absence of market failures, the competitiveness would be the same as comparative advantage. However, Kannapiran and Fleming (1999) point out that in the real world the above listed assumptions do not hold, in addition, there might be distortions due to government policies, hence competitiveness and comparative advantage are usually different.
Existing theories offer different approaches to explaining and measuring competitiveness. Attempts at systematization of these approaches have been recently made by Gellynck (2002); Hein (2006); Joeri (2006); Berkum (2004); Zawalinska (2004) and Siggel (2003). In a recent study Gellynck (2002), citing an earlier work by Buckley et al. (1988), makes a distinction between performance, potential and process with regard to competitiveness. Performance can be measured in terms of profitability, market share or trade balance. Potential is linked to advantages at the level of inputs such as production factors. Process deals with the question of how the potential is translated in performance. Consequently, a distinction can be made between two categories, namely measuring and explaining competitiveness, and the existing concepts on competitiveness can be grouped to two categories. Measuring competitiveness is limited to quantifying, while explaining goes beyond this in looking for independent variables or drivers of competitiveness. The approaches belonging to the second category and explains what the equations in the first category measure.
The PAM is a computational framework, developed by Monke and Pearson (1989) and augmented by Masters and Winter-Nelson (1995), for measuring input use efficiency in production, comparative advantage, and the degree of government interventions. The basis of the PAM is a set of profit and loss identities that are familiar to anyone in business (Nelson and Panggabean, 1991). The basic format of the PAM, as shown in Table 16, is a matrix of two-way accounting identities. The data in the first row provide a measure of private profitability (N), defined as the difference between observed revenue (A) and cost (B+C). Private profitability demonstrates the competitiveness of the agricultural system, given current technologies, prices for inputs and outputs, and policy. The second row of the matrix calculates the social profit that reflects social opportunity cost. Social profits measure efficiency and comparative advantage. In addition, comparison of private and social profits provides a measure of efficiency. A positive social profit indicates that the country uses scarce resources efficiently and has a static comparative advantage in the production of that commodity at the margin. Similarly, negative social profits suggest that the sector is wasting resources that could have been utilized more efficiently in some other sector. In other words, the cost of domestic production exceeds the cost of imports, suggesting that the sector cannot survive without government support at the margin. The third row of the matrix estimates the difference between the first and second rows. The difference between private and social values of revenues, costs, and profits can be explained by policy interventions.
Table 16 Policy Analysis Matrix
Value of output | Value of input | Profit | ||
Tradable | Domestic factor | |||
Private prices | A | B | C | N |
Social prices | D | E | F | O |
Policy transfer | G | H | I | P |
Source: Monke and Pearson, 1989
Note: Private profit: N=A-(B+C), Social profit: O=D(E+F), Output transfer: G=A-D, Input transfer:
H=B-E, Factor transfer: I=C-F, Net policy transfer: P=N-O
The PAM framework can also be used to calculate important indicators for policy analysis. Computations of these indicators are as follows below
3.3.1 The Nominal Protection Coefficient (NPC)
Nominal Protection Coefficient (NPC) of Indian pomegranate and gherkin was estimated in order to examine its export competitiveness in the World market. Nominal Protection Coefficient is a straightforward measure of competitiveness. It is calculated as a ratio between the domestic prices to the International price of a comparable grade of commodity, adjusted for all the transfer costs such as freight, insurance, handling costs, margins, losses etc. If NPC is less than one, the commodity is competitive (as per importable hypothesis, it is considered a good import substitute and under exportable hypothesis, it is worth exporting). If NPC is greater than one, the commodity is not competitive (not a good import substitute or not worth exporting).
a) Nominal Protection Coefficient on Output (NPCO)
This ratio shows the extent to which domestic prices for output differ from international reference prices. If NPCO is greater than one, the domestic farm gate price is greater than the international price of output and thus the system receives protection. On the contrary if NPCO is less than one, the system is disprotected by policy. NPCO is expressed as
NPCO = A / D
b) Nominal Protection Coefficient on Input (NPCI)
This ratio shows how much domestic prices for tradable inputs differ from their social prices. If NPCI exceeds one, the domestic input cost is greater than the comparable world prices and thus the system is taxed by policy. If NPCI is less than one, the system is subsidized by policy. Using the PAM framework, NPCI is derived as
NPCI= B/E
3.3.2 Effective protection coefficient (EPC)
EPC is the ratio of value added in private prices (A-B) to value added in social prices (E-F). An EPC value of greater than one suggests that government policies provide positive incentives to producers while values less than one indicate that producers are not protected through policy interventions.
EPC= (A-B)/(D-E)
3.3.3 Domestic resource cost (DRC)
DRC, the most useful indicator among four, is used to compare the relative efficiency or comparative advantage among agricultural commodities. It is defined as the shadow value of non tradable factor inputs used in an activity per unit of tradable value added (F/(D-E)). The DRC indicates whether the use of domestic factors is socially profitable (DRC1). A state will have a comparative advantage in a given crop if the value of the DRC for that crop is lower than the DRC for other crops grown in that state. Although the DRC indicator is widely used in academic research, its primary use has been in applied works by the World Bank, FAO, and International Food Policy Research Institute(IFPRI) to measure comparative advantage in developing countries.
DRC= F/(D-E)
3.3.4 Private Cost Ratio (PCR)
PCR is the ratio of factor costs (C) to value added in private prices (A-B). This ratio measures the competitiveness of a commodity system at the farm level. The system is competitive if the PCR is less than 1. Using the PAM framework the PCR can be expressed as follows
PRC=C/(A-B)
The data requirement for constructing a PAM includes yield, input requirement, and the market prices for inputs and outputs. This is collected from primary and secondary data. The primary data on production aspects of gherkin and pomegranate was collected from Tumkur and Bijapur district of Karnataka, India. Secondary data pertaining to area, production and exports were collected for country as a whole from the government institutions, APEDA, Market associations and also from the exporters of fruits and vegetables. Additional data such as transportation costs, port charges, storage costs, production subsidies, import/export tariffs, and exchange rates are also required to calculate a social price which is collected from the exporters of pomegranate and gherkin from Karnataka. In this study, a PAM will be compiled for pomegranate and gherkin.
Most of the data related to study is collected from the primary source especially Cost of Cultivation of pomegranate and gherkin crops in Karnataka, India. Two stage simple random sampling procedure was adopted for the study. Out of twenty six districts, two districts (Tumkur for gherkin and Bijapur for pomegranate) was selected in the first stage and in the second stage 80 farmers was selected, consisting of 40 farmers in each district cultivating pomegranate and gherkin respectively. Each district is demarcated into homogenous agro-climatic zones based on cropping pattern, soil types, rainfall, and other features. The most difficult tasks for constructing a PAM are estimating social prices for outputs and inputs and decomposing the inputs into tradable and non-tradable components. For computing social prices for various commodities, including both outputs and inputs, world prices are used as the reference price in the study. We choosed U.A.E and Netherlands as reference prices for pomegranate and gherkin since these two countries are major importers. These world prices are obtained from various commodities by referring to officially published source by the different Department of Agriculture all over the world, Ministry of Agriculture from India, and also from export institution like APEDA. The world prices are adjusted for transportation costs and marketing costs to be comparable with farm gate prices. For imported commodities, social prices at the farm gate are calculated by adding marketing costs from the respective CIF Mumbai prices (calculated by adding the ocean freight charge to the FOB price) in domestic currency. Similarly, for exported commodities, social prices at the farm gate are calculated by adding the marketing cost from the respective world reference price in the domestic currency, converted to foreign currency. These prices are converted to domestic currencies using market exchange rates. Finally, marketing costs are added to compare with farm gate prices. Following Pursell and Gupta (1999), marketing costs consist of an interest charge for two months at an 18 percent rate applied to the CIF prices plus INR10 per metric ton to represent other marketing expenses. Similar procedures are used for calculating input shadow prices for fertilizers and pesticides. The social valuation of land is calculated by taking lease value prevailing in that area. Based on Monke and Pearson (1989), who suggested that decomposing all input costs is a tedious task and yields a merely a very insignificant effect on result. Some inputs such as land, labor, farm capital depreciation, animal power, and manure are assumed to be totally non tradable. Once the inputs are disaggregated into tradable and non tradable components, PAM is constructed for pomegranate and gherkin.
The determination of social values is one of the main tasks of economists, since these values offer the best indication of optimizing income and social welfare. In case of domestic factors, which are not traded on international markets, figuring out social prices is difficult and one way to do so involves mentally subtracting the effects of policy. The social costs have been calculated using Value Marginal Product approach, which uses factor share (Si) of various inputs (Xi ) together with the mean values of inputs and outputs (Y) and prices (Pi) . The computation of the social cost of input is as follows.
Pi=[(Si/Xi ) Yi]Py
Once all private values have been matched with their social equivalents, we arrive at two identities:
Private revenue - Private cost of tradable inputs - Private cost of domestic factors
= Private profit
Social revenue - Social cost of tradable inputs - Social cost of domestic factors = Social profit.
The opportunities and constraints in cultivation and export of gherkin and pomegranate were collected from the primary data both from farmers and exporters. Garrett's ranking technique was used to analyze both opportunities and constraints. Basically it gives the change of orders for constraints, advantages into numerical scores. The major advantage of this technique as compared to simple frequency distribution is that the constraints and advantages are arranged based on their importance from the point of view of respondents. Hence the same number of respondents on two or more constraints may have been given different rank Kumar et al. (1999).
The percent position of each rank is then converted into scores referring to the table given by Garret and Woodswordh (1969). For each factors, the scores of individual respondents were added together and divided the total number of the respondents for whom scores were added. These mean scores for all the factors were arranged in descending order, ranks were given and most important factors were identified.
Arunkumar et al. (1980) studied the financial aspects of potato in Karnataka and reported that, the total operational cost of potato per hectare in Bangalore in irrigated condition was INR 9558 and in rainfed condition was INR 3567. On the other hand, the operational cost in Hassan amounted to INR 10346 under irrigated conditions and INR 3601 under rainfed condition. The returns from the irrigated and rainfed conditions were INR 12336 and INR 4800, respectively. Further they observed that expenditure on seed (tuber) accounted for 20 percent of the total cost, fertilizers and FYM accounted for 35 percent and labour accounted for 23 percent.
Lohar (1987) studied the economics and marketing of hybrid tomatoes in Sara district (Maharastra state). He found that the per hectare cost of cultivation of hybrid tomato was INR 54698. He observed that the cost of marketing also was very expensive (INR 28297.71 per hectare) and it accounted for nearly 52 percent of the total cost and consumed almost 25 percent of the gross income. Further, he noticed that rental value of land, manures and fertilizers, human labour; other expenses (such as bamboo sutali for tying the bamboo) and plant protection charges were the major cost items and accounted for 33 percent of the total cost. The per quintal cost of production worked out INR 74.09 .Of the total marketing cost incurred by the producers, 55.31 percent was towards transport charges. 40.95 percent towards wooden boxes, 1.02 percent for sutali and 0.87 percent of bamboo boxes. The per quintal marketing costs was INR 38.33. The gross profit realized from the sale of 738.20 quintals of hybrid tomatoes was INR 115903.11 and thus, the net return, after deducting the cost of cultivation and marketing worked out to INR 32902.40 per hectare.
Karisomangoudar (1990) studied the economics of production and marketing of rainfed onion in Gadag taluk of Dharwad district. He found that the total cost of production of rainfed onion was INR 2777.43 for small producers and INR 3788.63 for large producers. In onion production, human labour was a major cost item and accounted for 40.14 percent for small producers and 30.06 percent of total cost of cultivation for 16.28 percent and 29.97 percent for small and large producers, respectively. The net returns obtained by small producers were lower (INR 3647.07) when compared to large producers (INR 5317.27) per acre. Cost of production per quintal was INR 86.54 for small and INR 96.78 for large producers.
Kallsen et al. (2000) assessed the costs and returns of pistachio (100 acres) in California. The study showed that Benefit- Cost ratio (total costs / total benefits) was 1.32 and net return above total cost was US$ -591
Riazi (2005) conducted a study on challenges and suggestion for Iran's Pistachio production and exports. The study revealed that the low productivity per hectare is the main challenge that Pistachio industry has faced. Increasing cultivation area, in recent years cannot guarantee the profitability of production and also the first position of Iran in global production and marketing in future. He suggested for conducting related research to overcome the problem with aim to increase the production per unit area .Also administrative policies and looking for new markets should be considered to facilitate a profitable production as well as a consistent market.
In this study we apply policy analysis matrix model which is widely used to analyze the competitiveness of pomegranate and gherkin from India. In this section we are reviewing the existing literature concerned to policy analysis matrix models, and also competitiveness of fruits and vegetables from all over the world. Many of these literatures pertaining to the core subject of this thesis are discussed below.
Jony (2003) analyzed the efficiency and competition of soybeans farming System in Jember by using the Policy Analysis Matrix methodology. The results demonstrated that, even at the current levels of productivity, soybeans yield a profitable return to land and management at both private and social prices. Farmers who have switched to the new seeds developed by Indonesian researchers have been able to increase productivity (and profits) substantially. And also finding suggests that government efforts to reintroduce import tariffs on soybeans which would be undesirable leading to inefficiencies in the use of domestic resources.
Samarendu Mohanty et al. (2002) developed a modified policy analysis matrix (PAM) approach to assess the efficiency of cotton production in five major producing states in India. The results indicate that cotton is not efficiently produced especially in second-largest cotton-producing country in the world. Without government interventions in the appeared states, it is likely that acreage will move away from cotton to more profitable crops such as sugarcane and groundnut. In addition, he concluded that cotton is not the most efficient crop produced in the four Indian states. However, there is at least one crop in each state that is less efficiently produced than cotton. His findings suggested that Indian policies directed at maintaining the availability of cheap cotton for the handloom and textile sectors have induced major inefficiencies in the cotton sector.
Joachim et al. (2002) discussed the impact of Government policy on clove production in Minahasa Regency. He attributed that due to an unusually high clove price in 2001 (Rp . 70,000 per kg), the government's proposed Rp. 2,000 per kilo price was only 2.8% of the farmer's profits. If the government used these revenues to carry out research on clove production, especially fertilizer application, if they create an effective extension service, the tax could lead to greater profits in the future. Further they also discussed Farmers fear on tax revenues will simply disappear into operational expenses. They also fear that the price of cloves will revert to long-term trends that are half the price registered in 2001. Whereas divergences between private and social prices in clove production are minimal.
Joko Sutrisno et al. (2003) analyzed the competitiveness of red onion production in brebes, central java. The results of the farm budget analysis show that both technologies are profitable at private and social prices. Onions, for Brebes farmers, have a comparative advantage over other crops that could grow in the dry season. The imported seed technology, however, gave substantially higher profits than the traditional technology. This was primarily due to the difference in yields. Farmers using the traditional technology obtained 8,509 kg/ha. Others using the imported seed technology received 13369 kg/ha. Private profits for traditional technology were INR 6 623464 per hectare; profits for improved technology were INR 13315929 per hectare. The number of farmers using the improved technology is small and it is unclear why more farmers have not adopted the improved seed package. There are virtually no policy distortions in onion red production. The study showed that the only significant difference between private and social prices occurred as a result of a small import tariff on pesticides.
The PAM-based research on competitiveness and efficiency of potato farming in pangalengan by Elly and Iis (2004) shows that all three production systems by using certified, domestic and imported seed are highly profitable at both private and social prices. However, plots using certified seed were significantly more profitable compare to domestic or imported seed. As there are significant economies of scale in creating and enforcing a certification program, the results of the study suggest that developing such a project might be a good investment for the West Java Government.
Robinson Pellokila et al. (2004) analysed the impact of technology improvement on the profitability of soe keprok citrus farming in timor tengah selatan by using NPV of PAMs. The result show strong positive towards private and social profit of farming SoE Keprok citrus in Tobu, Netpala, and Ajaobaki and all these three regions enjoy competitive and comparative advantages. Keprok citrus production is extremely profitable and efficient in Tobu because farmers in the region have benefited from the OECF project that has introduced improved inputs (chemical fertilizers and pesticides) and better farming practices (weeding and pruning). Divergences in the prices of output (and revenues) have resulted from the 16% import tariff on citrus. The output divergences ranged between 11% and 18%, reflecting differences in local transportation costs in the studied places.
Gorton et al. (2001) analyzed the international competitiveness of Polish Agriculture by using the DRC on the base of three farm sizes and eight commodities. They stated during the period 1996 to 1998 Polish crop productions was more internationally competitive than livestock farming. They found the inverse relationship between the DRCs and farm size.
Inocencio and David (1995) analyzed the international competitiveness of Philippine Rice production period ranging from 1966 to 1990. They said that neither the irrigated nor rainfed areas showed any comparative advantage in 1966 as evidenced by their DRCs that are greater than the shadow exchange rate.
Gorton et al. (2000) considered the competitiveness of agricultural production in Bulgaria and Czech Republic compared to international markets and EU by using the revealed comparative advantage (RCA) and domestic resource cost (DRC). They said that DRC estimations indicate that Czech and Bulgaria cereal producers were competitive at world market prices as well as at the EU prices. However, they did not show RCA in trade with EU.
Islam Nural (1990) mentioned that the entry of horticultural products produced and the export market was constrained due to the lack of specialized nature of export-related infrastructure. It includes strict quality and sanitation standards as well as established consumer preferences for specific products in particular markets. The author concluded that organization of an effective system of packing, processing, storage, transportation and distribution, both nationally and internationally, was crucial to success in horticultural exports.
Vyas (1994) suggested the following preconditions in order to increase export of fruits, vegetables, flowers, etc., they are (a) vertical integration of small holdings with appropriate secondary and tertiary organizations for input supply, quality control, marketing and processing (b) The infrastructure support in terms of communication, transport, cold storage, etc., (c) Development of economic and social infrastructure.
Chakrapani (1994) reported that no attention has been paid to develop the export of fruits and vegetables in India. Fruits and vegetables worth Rs 203 crore were exported from India mainly to UAE and UK during 1992-93. However, these products being perishable needed proper attention at all stages right from marketing. But, unfortunately sufficient attention has not been paid in this direction
Thakur et al. (1994) identified the problems encountered by the farmers in marketing the vegetables. They are (1) unorganized market and low prices paid to farmers (2) lack of mechanical grading, packing and proper storage facilities (3) Malpractice, high and undue marketing margins, (4) lack of sufficient and low cost transportation facilities, (5) lack of market information and market news, and (6) lack of processing units and co operative societies.
Sharanesh (1994) reported that unavailability of labour was the major problem in the cultivation of grapes in Bijapur districts of Karnataka. This problem is still more in vineyards with narrow spacing where more labours are required for each farm operation. About 32.25 percent of farmers stated problem of heavy initial investment and also problem of high incidence of pest and diseases which affect whole vineyard if not controlled in time.
Gopal Rao (1998) studied the export of horticultural crops from Andra Pradesh and observed that, mangoes and onions were exported in large quantities to foreign countries. The major constraint in the way of increasing export of fruits and vegetables to the International markets were poor quality, premature harvesting of the fruits leading to reduced shelf life and low sugar content, lack of adequate knowledge of the quality standards in International market by both farmers as well as the merchants, poor storage and transport facilities, carelessness in handlings of fruits and vegetables at various stages of picking, packing and transportation. Thus, the author opinioned that the promotion of export of fruits and vegetables in the State needs dissemination of knowledge on International standards of quality, export policies, duties, subsidies and taxes, freight, etc., to all stake-holders form growers to exporters as well as strict supervision and control on quality for export.
Praduman Kumar and Subarthi (1998) stated that, despite nurturing a wide variety of fruits, which enjoyed comparative advantages in their production and export, India had not been able to do well on the horticulture export front. The main reasons which hampered the field from growing according to the author were high cost of raw materials, in adequate and expensive refrigeration facilities during storage, transportation and distribution. He further reasoned that poor availability and high cost of quality packaging, related machinery, inefficient existing technologies and high residual effects contributed to the problems. To strengthen these activities, the study suggested to diversify and expand the export basket giving due emphasis to the development of domestic market simultaneously and infrastructure facilities.
Smitha (2004) studied the major problems in production by anthurium growers in Coorg districts in Karnataka. High cost of the planting materials and the huge initial investment required for the cultivation of anthurium, the problem of pests and disease attack and also the low light intensity during winter season were considered to be important problems which reduced the productivity of crop drastically during winter. Reza (2005) studied the main constraints in the production and marketing, trade of pistachio in Iran. High cost of production, unstable domestic market, low productivity and non-availability of required quantity and quality of planting materials, incidence of pest and diseases were the major constraints in the production and trade. As water shortage and salinity is the major constraint in the production which substantially caused reduction in orchard productivity. The other major problems listed include high cost of water pumping and all other allied cost to the farmers.
The chapter deals with the policy analysis matrix developed in the preceding chapter to analyze the export competitiveness and efficiency of gherkin and pomegranate from India. Further the hypothesis put forth in the first chapter was tested with the simulation results and it explains the rationale behind the results. In this chapter we also present the economics as well as the constraints in production and export of gherkin and pomegranate from India.
The result of the analysis of gherkin cultivation is given in Table 17. The total cost of cultivation was worked out to be INR 23631 per acre per crop of gherkin. Out of which the variable costs for seeds, FYM, fertilizers, PPC, labour, staking materials and interest on working capital amounted to INR 22429. This showed that the farmer had to invest more in the production of gherkin in the three month period. Hence there was a huge demand for capital to undertake gherkin cultivation. Among the variable inputs, staking material was a crucial step in gherkin cultivation which helped to get better crop and quality produce. The fixed costs or long term investment covered INR 1201 of the total cost of cultivation of gherkin.
One of the healthy practices followed by the sample farmers was their investment on FYM which amounts to INR 1403 out of the total cost of cultivation. The fact revealed that the farmers were more concerned about soil fertility. The irrigation costs accounted for only INR 821 of total cost of cultivation which never reflects its true value. Mainly because the electricity for lifting the water was not priced on pro rata basis, instead the farmers were charged a flat price based on the horse power of the motor used to lift the same
One of the most important things in gherkin production was the investment made in labor. More than two third of total cost of cultivation was invested in the form of labour wages. Labour is important for grading which is done cautiously to get more small sized fruits, which helps in fetching them premium price in market. High labor requirement shifted the gherkin production from West to developing countries where wages are low.
Since India is having large labor force in agriculture, the cultivation of gherkin was justified in this ground. Since grading was done in gherkin, the yield from an acre was given as per the grades fixed by the contracting company. The yield of the Grade I, II and III fruit was more since the returns from these Grades are higher INR 20700, INR 13222 and INR 6891 respectively (Table 18). The total gross return from one acre gherkin is INR 43837. The net return from an acre of gherkin production is worked out to be INR 20207. That implied gherkin was a highly remunerative crop. Since the crop is grown under contract system, the return was assured and this has become a lucrative business option for the farmers in that area.
Table 17 Cost of cultivation of gherkin (per crop per acre)
Particulars | INR /acre |
Variable cost | |
Seeds | 3026.02 |
FYM | 1403.02 |
Seeds Fertilizers | 2218.90 |
Plant protection chemicals | 3207.31 |
Irrigation cost | 820.54 |
Labour | 8031.79 |
Staking materials |
2060.14 |
Interest on working capital @ 8% | 1661.41 |
Fixed cost | |
Land rent |
502.01 |
Interest on fixed cost @ 10% | 48.96 |
Yield (kg) | |
a. Grade I | 2300.34 |
b. Grade II | 1763.71 |
c. Grade III | 1253.12 |
d. Grade IV | 602.10 |
e. Grade V | 458.83 |
Total cost of cultivation | 23630.60 |
Source: Author based on the empirical result
Table 18 Returns of gherkin per crop per acre
Grades | INR |
a. Grade I (INR 9/kg) | 20700 |
b. Grade II (INR 7.5/kg) | 13223 |
c. Grade III (INR 5.5/kg) | 6891 |
d. Grade IV (INR 3.5/kg) | 2107 |
e. Grade V (INR 2/kg) | 916 |
Gross returns | 43837 |
Source: Author based on the empirical result
Pomegranate is the second most widely cultivated crop by the respondent of Bijapur taluk who were highly innovative and cultivated many varieties of pomegranate (Bhagva, Mrudula, Araktha, Ganesha and Jyothi) which were new to other parts of the state. All the costs pertaining to cultivation of pomegranate were grouped into two, major categories namely establishment costs (Land preparation, fencing, planting layers, transport of plant layers, opening pits, filling and planting and staking) and production costs (cost of fertilizers, plant protection chemicals, farm yard manure, labour and irrigation cost).
Table 19 shows that the pomegranate cultivators had invested INR 19964 on establishment and INR 11870 on production during the first year. From the establishment costs farmers spent more on planting and plant filling materials which accounted for INR 7401. Establishment cost is incurred only during first year of crop cultivation. As production starts from second year, farmers incur only production costs. Since the yield starts from second year, production cost incurred by the farmers during the first year was less (INR 11870) compared to second year (INR 17868), third year (INR 23625) fourth year (INR 27273) and fifth year (INR 30163) of pomegranate production. Out of the production costs, farmers incurred more on irrigation during first year (INR 5000). Total costs include establishment costs and production costs for one acre of pomegranate cultivation per year. Total costs continued to increased from first year to fifth year due to the fact that, successive years plants bore more fruits that require more inputs compared to the initial years of crop production.
As the pomegranate starts yielding from second year onwards, farmers harvested 937 kg/acre, 2437 kg/acre, 3058 kg/acre and 3862 kg/ acre by fetching a price of INR 15 /kg, INR 17/kg, INR 18/kg and INR 18/kg during the second , third, fourth and fifth years of pomegranate production respectively. Gross returns worked out to be INR 14060, INR 41443, INR 55045 and INR 69525 per acre during the second, third, fourth and fifth years respectively.
Table 19 Cost of cultivation of pomegranate (per crop per acre)
Particulars | I year | II year | III year | IV year | V year |
Establishment costs | |||||
Land preparation | 3869 | ||||
Fencing | 2723 | ||||
Planting layers | 4506 | ||||
Transport of plant layers | 808 | ||||
Opening pits | 1859 | ||||
Filling and planting | 2895 | ||||
Staking | 3304 | ||||
Sub total | 19964 | ||||
Production costs | |||||
Cost of fertilizers | 1561 | 2497 | 3500 | 3855 | 4100 |
Cost of PPC | 1280 | 3383 | 3649 | 4750 | 4800 |
Cost of FYM | 1800 | 2494 | 3502 | 3800 | 4000 |
Labour cost | 2229 | 4494 | 7974 | 9868 | 12263 |
Irrigation cost | 5000 | 5000 | 5000 | 5000 | 5000 |
Total cost | 31834 | 17868 | 23625 | 27273 | 30163 |
Yield (kg/acre) | 0 | 937 | 2437 | 3058 | 3862 |
Price (INR /kg) | 0 | 15 | 17 | 18 | 18 |
Gross returns | 0 | 14060 | 41443 | 55045 | 69525 |
Source: Author based on the empirical result
Efficiency refers to the ability of a farming system to earn profit at efficient or social prices, those that reflect the absence of distorting policies and market failures which in turn leads to higher income for the country. On the other hand competitiveness reflects the ability of a farming system to earn profits at the actual market or private prices in place where the study was carried out. The PAM in Table 20 shows that the gherkin production earns private profit of Rs 20206.42 per acre which indicates that a firm is competitive under the market conditions it faces. While social profits of about INR 49725.55 per acre indicate that the activity is competitive under world market conditions and that the domestic factors are used efficiently in this sector. In this case, the policy has significant impact on the farm profit may be the exchange rate which considerably reduces farm revenues by INR 33425. The negative divergences between the private and social values of tradable inputs (INR 920.93) indicate world market prices for tradable inputs are higher than the domestic prices. The overall effect of the policy under this scenario would be has negative transfer of INR 29519 per acre away from gherkin growers. It illustrates the lack of policy effects and market failure in gherkin production. In spite of the negative transfer, gherkin cultivation can still offer farmers attractive private profits. In other words, a negative divergence between private and social profit implies that the net effect of policy intervention is reduction of profitability of gherkin production at farm level. A removal of policy distortions would increase profitability to further extent. The negative output transfers were caused mainly by disprotection policies of the government's prevailing policies.
Table 20 PAM of gherkin production
Revenue | Tradable inputs | Domestic inputs | Profit | |
Private | 43837.00 | 8452.11 | 15178.47 | 20206.42 |
Social | 77262.40 | 9373.04 | 15178.47 | 49725.55 |
Divergence | -33425.4 | -920.93 | -2985.34 | -29519.1 |
Source: Author based on the empirical result
Indicators of gherkin farming are presented in Table 21. The ratio formed to measure output transfer is called NPCO. In the present study the NPCO value of gherkin is 0.57 which indicates that gherkin farmers received lower prices than they would have received at world price that implies the system was disprotected. On the input side, the NPCI was less than one (0.9) for the gherkin production which shows that the policy regime favors farmers and reduces the cost of tradable inputs to some extent.
DRC is an indicator of social profit or efficiency. It is the ratio of social opportunity cost of domestic factors of production relative to the value added in the world prices. DRC value of 0.27 indicates positive social profit and shows that the gherkin production is economically efficient and the country has a comparative advantage in the gherkin production. In other words, the gherkin production is extremely efficient in India as DRC value is much less than one. Elly and Lis during 2004 in their study on the competitiveness and efficiency of potato farming in Pangalengan, Indonesia obtained similar results where DRC values of certified, domestic and imported potato farming were 0.25, 0.31 and 0.29 respectively, indicating positive social profits. They concluded that the country has an economically efficient and comparative advantage in producing potato.
The PCR indicates private profit or competitiveness. PCR value of 0.43 is obtained from the ratio of the private opportunity cost of domestic factors of production relative to the value added in domestic prices. This value indicates positive private profit which shows that the gherkin production is competitive for resources given the actual prices in the product and factor markets.
EPC is a more reliable indicator of the effective incentives than the NPC. It indicates the impact of protection on inputs and outputs and reveals the degree of protection accorded to the value added process in the production activity of the relevant commodity. The EPC value of 0.52 shows that the gherkin farmers face a net tax of around 50 percent on their value added. In other words it indicates that there is no subsidy in gherkin production and also for the tradable input markets from government policies. The costs or prices of gherkin producers is 48 percent less than that would have been in the absence of policy on output and tradable inputs.
Table 21 Results of the indicators for gherkin production and export
Indicators | Result |
NPCO | 0.57 |
NPCI | 0.90 |
EPC | 0.52 |
DRC | 0.27 |
PCR | 0.43 |
Source: based on the Empirical Result
Pomegranate is an important commercial crop and production occurs over a period of 15 to 18 years. An analysis of competitiveness and efficiency requires that these results be discounted to net present value. The present value obtained for pomegranate production can be measured through the construction of PAM. The analysis begins with the calculations of existing levels of private (actual market) and social (efficiency) revenues, costs and profits. The result of the PAM analysis shows that (Table 22) the Pomegranate production is privately and socially profitable in India. There are high divergence between private and social prices for revenue (INR 247548) and profits (INR 232552) whereas small divergences between tradable (INR 8547) and non tradable inputs (INR 6449). The divergences result from either distorting policies or market failures.
Social prices for pomegranate are higher than private prices which in turn indicates that India will be an important potential pomegranate producing country instead of being an importer. At the same time farmers are paying higher prices for the inputs than the world price. The reason for higher prices of tradable inputs is due to the policy distortion resulting from import duties imposed on them. Instead of providing subsidies, the government imposes import duties on tradable inputs causing an increase in domestic market prices. This particular policy creates a positive transfer shown by the negative divergences between private and social values of tradable inputs. Since the world market prices for tradable inputs are higher than the domestic prices, India would have benefited from domestic tradable inputs by taking advantage of lower prices of domestic tradable inputs.
Table 22 PAM of pomegranate production
Social48821855496120038312684 Divergence-247548-8547-6449-232552
Revenue | Tradable inputs | Domestic inputs | Profit | |
Private | 240670 | 46949 | 113589 | 80132 |
Source: Author based on the Empirical Result
As per Table 23 PCR (0.59) and DRC (0.28) values are lower than one indicates that pomegranate production in India have competitive and comparative advantages. These values also indicate that the domestic resource value of production is lower than the output level measured in the world market prices. Further, the DRC value indicates positive social profit and shows that the production system is economically efficient and the country has a comparative advantage in producing within the system. The lower the DRC, the greater is the degree of economic efficiency. In this study PCR value indicates a positive private profit and shows that the pomegranate production system is competitive for resources given the actual prices in the factor and product markets.
NPCO (0.49) is less than one, suggesting that the domestic price of pomegranate is below the international price. Similarly NPCI (0.84) is also less than one, indicating that the government policies are reducing input costs for pomegranate. In other words input subsidies lead to NPCI smaller than one. Mohanty et al. (2002) assessed the competitiveness of cotton from five states of India and his result reveals NPC values of cotton production from all five states are less than one for all inputs and outputs. It clearly shows that the government efforts to support the textile sectors by providing raw cotton at a cheaper price. EPC (0.45) is less than one, indicating that the producers are not protected through policy interventions.
Table 23 Results of the indicators for pomegranate production and export
Indicators | Result |
NPCO | 0.49 |
NPCI | 0.84 |
EPC | 0.45 |
DRC | 0.28 |
PCR | 0.59 |
Source: based on the empirical result
Garret ranking technique was adapted to find out the constraints in production of gherkin and pomegranate from India.
4.7.1 Constraints in production of gherkin
The farmers sampled were asked about the various constraints faced by them in gherkin production. Since it is one of the export oriented vegetable crop grown under the contract farming, the company provides all inputs and production services like access of credit, guaranteed and fixed pricing strategies, access to reliable markets. Hence there are no major constraints and the only problem is the availability of labour that remains a bottleneck in the production of gherkin.
4.7.2 Constraints in production of pomegranate
Pomegranate is one of the important commercial crop and it is labour intensive. Further, some of the operations like pruning, weeding and harvesting require skilled labours. The non-availability of such a skilled labour with a Garret score of 73 was the major production constraint expressed by pomegranate cultivators of study area (Table 24).Similar observations have been made by Sharanesh (1994) in Bijapur district of Karnataka, where 67.5 per cent of the farmers expressed the same problem of un availability of skilled labours. The next most important problem that the growers expressed was high incidence of pest and diseases with a Garret score of 61. The producers were apprehensive of taking up chemical pesticides as the crop was exclusively cultivated for export and they were afraid of rejection due to any pesticide residue. Improper transportation and high cost of inputs received the third and fourth rank respectively. Cold storage facilities and low net returns were the other problems listed. Pomegranate being an intensive crop requires higher use of inputs like fertilizer, water and labour and as a result the cost of cultivation is high. The cultivators of pomegranate in the study area expressed that the institutional credit availability was inadequate to meet high expenses. Smitha (2004) observed similar problems in the cultivation of anthurium in Coorg district of Karnataka, where high cost of planting materials and huge initial investment were the major problems.
Table 24 Production constraints of pomegranate in India.
Sl. No | Constraints | Score | Rank |
1 |
Non availability of skilled labour |
73 |
1 |
2 | High incidence of pest and diseases | 61 | 2 |
3 | Lack of transportation facilities | 50 | 3 |
4 | High cost of inputs | 48 | 4 |
5 | Lack of adequate cold storage facilities | 34 | 5 |
6 | Low revenue | 32 | 6 |
Source: Author, based on the Empirical Result
Garret ranking technique was adapted to find out the constraints in export of gherkin and pomegranate from India
4.8.1 Constraints in export of gherkin
The sample exporters of gherkin were asked about the various constraints faced by them in the export of gherkin. The Garrett's Ranking Technique was used and the results are presented in Table 25. From the table, it is evident that the lack of superior quality compared to international standards (Phyto-sanitary measures) and lack of adequate export promotional measures, with a garret score of 73 and 71 respectively are the main constraints faced by the exporters in the export of gherkin, in order of importance as perceived by them
Besides, lack of infrastructural facilities, lack of adequate packaging and processing technologies and poor international marketing intelligence are the other constraints in gherkin exports. This is consistent with the similar studies by Mitra (1991), Sundaresan and Preeti Menon (1994) and Gursharan Singh Kainth (1996).
Table 25 Constraints in export of gherkin
Sl. No | Constraints | Score | Rank |
1 |
Lack of superior fronts in international market |
73 |
1 |
2 | Lack of adequate export promotional measures | 71 | 2 |
3 | Lack of infrastructural facilities | 58 | 3 |
4 | Lack of adequate packaging and processing technologies | 51 | 4 |
5 | Poor international marketing intelligence | 49 | 5 |
Source: Author, based on the Empirical Result
4.8.2 Constraints in export of pomegranate
Major constraints experienced in the export of pomegranate by the exporters in the study area are presented in the Table 26. High pesticide residual effect with a score of 69 is an important constraint faced by the pomegranate exporters. These constraints are in consordance with the findings of Pradhumn (1998). European consumers are highly sensitive to pesticide residues in consumable products. It therefore recommends special research and developmental efforts to overcome these problems by introducing pest and disease resistant varieties. It also emphasizes biological control methods in integrated management of insect pests to reduce the use of pesticides in cultivation and educate the pomegranate growers.
Exporters complained on lack of proper transportation and cold storage facility, improper pre-cooling and fluctuation in storage temperature, leading to post harvest decay. Transportation involving long distance required long lasting storage facility. Exporters expressed a keen interest to acquire these facilities but the major impediment remains huge initial investments. They expressed the need of Government to extend more financial support to co-operatives and other export agencies for acquisition of such facilities. Exporters are also ranked unavailability of labour and limited availabilities of exportable varieties as other important problems for the export of pomegranate from India.
Table 26 Constraints in pomegranate exports from India
Sl. No | Constraints | Score | Rank |
1 |
High residual effect |
69 |
1 |
2 | Non availability of skilled labour | 60 | 2 |
3 | Lack of transportation facilities | 53 | 3 |
4 | Lower productivity of export variety | 47 | 4 |
5 | Lack of adequate cold storage facilities | 39 | 5 |
6 | Planting materials | 37 | 6 |
Source: Author, based on the Empirical Result
The hypothesis regarding the export competitiveness of gherkin and pomegranate from India as listed in the introductory chapter is tested and presented in the following section along with the results.
The overall result shows that, the cultivation of gherkin and pomegranate are economically profitable whereas farmers are getting net returns of INR 20207 in the case of gherkin. In case of pomegranate the farmers started getting net returns from 3rd year onwards which amounted to INR 17818, INR 27772 and INR 39362 in the 3rd,4th and 5th year respectively. Export of Gherkin and pomegranate are competitive and efficient in international markets. According to the results obtained we can say that the hypothesis proposed is true. DRC value of 0.27 indicates positive social profit and shows that the gherkin production is economically efficient and the country has a comparative advantage in the gherkin production. PCR value of 0.43 indicates positive private profit which in turn shows that the gherkin production is competitive for resources, given the actual prices in the product and the factor market. In case of pomegranate PCR (0.59) and DRC (0.28) values are lower than one indicating that pomegranate production in India have competitive and comparative advantages. So we can safely conclude that the export of gherkin and pomegranate from India are competitive and efficient in international markets.
The result for Garret ranking in case of gherkin shows that skilled labour and lack of superior quality are the major constraints in production and export of gherkin respectively. In case of pomegranate non availability of skilled labour, high incidence of pest and diseases, lack of transportation facilities, high residual effect of pesticide are the major constrain in production and export.
Horticultural products have high income elasticity of demand, as income goes up the demand raises rapidly. It grows especially in middle and high income developing countries. As people are more cautious on health and nutrition, there is a paradigm shift from high fat, high cholesterol foods such as meat and livestock products to low fat and low cholesterol foods such as fruits and vegetables. Since then, the world has changed its attention towards high value agricultural products. Hence, it is crucial to be competitive in the world market to reap the potential gains of increased and growing world demand for horticultural products such as fruits and vegetables. Thus, the purpose of the present study attempts to evaluate the consequences of international trade and competitiveness of Indian horticulture with special reference to pomegranate and gherkin crops with the following objectives
Policy Analysis Matrix was applied to analyse the input use efficiency in production, comparative advantage, and the degree of government interventions in the production and export of gherkin and pomegranate from India. Further garret ranking technique is used to analyse the constraints in production and export of these two crops. Data regarding the production as well as export were collected from both primary and secondary sources. The primary data on production aspects of gherkin and pomegranate was collected from Tumkur and Bijapur district of Karnataka, India respectively. Secondary data pertaining to national exports was collected from the government institutions, APEDA, market associations and also from the exporters of fruits and vegetables. The salient findings of the study are presented below
Initial Cost of pomegranate cultivation for first year is INR 31834 due to establishment cost while for the second, third, fourth and fifth year, the cost of cultivation are INR 17868, INR 23625, INR 27273 and INR 30163 respectively. Gherkin farmers had realized higher gross and net returns (INR 43837and INR 20207 per acre respectively) Gross returns of pomegranate are INR 14060, INR 41443, INR 55045 and INR 69525 during second, third, fourth and fifth year respectively. Gherkin and pomegranate production systems in the study area were highly competitive which yielded the farmers a private profit of INR 20206 and INR 80132 respectively Both the production systems were highly efficient with a social profit of INR 49726 and INR 312684.
DRC of gherkin and pomegranate production were 0.27 and 0.28 showing strong comparative advantage. The measured divergences of gherkin and pomegranate between private and social levels of revenue (INR -33425 and INR -247548 respectively) and profit (INR -29519 and INR -232552 respectively) result from the significant distortion of policies or market failure. The factor was further influenced by gherkin and pomegranate prices. The net effect of government policies on output and input was to encourage gherkin and pomegranate production with profitability coefficient of 0.43 and 0.59 respectively.
The major constraint in gherkin production is reported to be the unavailability of labour. The other major impediments in the production of pomegranate were unavailability of skilled labour, high incidence of pest and diseases, improper transportation and high cost of inputs. The export of gherkin was further distorted by lack of superior quality compared to international standard, lack of adequate export promotional measures, lack of infrastructural facilities, lack of adequate packaging and processing technologies and poor international marketing intelligence as reported by the respondents.High pesticide residual, unavailability of skilled labour, lack of proper transportation and cold storage facilities were also identified as potential constraints in the export of pomegranate.
The Policy Analysis Matrix shows the effects of policies on the relative competitiveness of gherkin and pomegranate of India in world market. Strong private and social profit indicates that both the crops are enjoying competitive and comparative advantages. A negative divergence between private and social profit implies that the net effect of policy intervention reduced the profitability of gherkin and pomegranate in India. The removal of policy distortions would substantially increase profitability of farmers. The negative output transfers in selected crops were caused mainly by disprotection by the government's prevailing policies. The farmers receive lower revenue than they would have got in the absence of policy distortions. With a minor adjustment in the nominal rates of protection farmers can gain further private returns and the production systems would become more competitive.
Social prices for gherkin and pomegranate are higher than their private prices and it is mainly due to higher growth of demand coupled with protective policy. Positive social profit and the DRC ratio were less than unity implying that the gherkin and pomegranate production system uses scarce resources efficiently. It also indicates that both the production systems had strong economic efficiency in using domestic resources which exhibit comparative advantage in export. Overall, it indicates that the crop is potentially very beneficial to India in terms of DRC per unit of foreign exchange earned. On the other hand the competitiveness of systems is also measured by the private profitability (D) or PCR.
NPCO and EPC values of less than one indicate that the price structure discriminates or provides relative disincentives for growing this crop. As far as output prices are concerned India has a potential to be a producing country rather than importer of these two crops. In terms of policy implications, the estimates of NPC, EPC and DRC reveals that the removal of distortions in the output and input markets under trade liberalization if achieved, the growers of gherkin and pomegranate are likely to gain and the country will benefit more from production of these two crops. The NPCI for both production systems was less than one which indicates that the policies reduce input costs. This also indicates that both production systems were slightly subsidized by the policy on tradable inputs but it doesn't offer any important offset to the overall disprotection. As a result, EPC remains substantially less than unity. These results imply that there were significant disprotections from the Government to gherkin and pomegranate production system.
Finally we can conclude that under current profitable production conditions of gherkin and pomegranates, there is still a higher scope to increase the production and profit in the near future by the removal of market distortions by the government. The social profitability of these two crops will enhance the farmers' income and will contribute to the national economic growth.
Export competitiveness of high value horticultural crops in India. (2017, Jun 26).
Retrieved October 15, 2024 , from
https://studydriver.com/export-competitiveness-of-high-value-horticultural-crops-in-india/
A professional writer will make a clear, mistake-free paper for you!
Get help with your assignmentPlease check your inbox
Hi!
I'm Amy :)
I can help you save hours on your homework. Let's start by finding a writer.
Find Writer